Whether or not the Greek government receives a string-laden emergency loan from the the richer Eurozone countries or, less likely, the I.M.F., the lack of a coherent response from within the E.U. is disturbing in its own right. This is particularly relevant given the respective economic profiles of countries like Spain, Portugal, Ireland, and to a certain extent, Latvia and Estonia, all of which look disturbingly similar to Greece. That is, encasing the creamy, rich center of Europe, we have a host of economies with highly indebted governments, declining incomes, and an unhealthy dependency on foreign creditors. These countries are also either operating on the euro, or currencies pegged to it.
"If fears of contagion become widespread, risk-averse investors could start to gun for even the larger or 'stronger' euro zone economies and their debt," said Geoffrey Yu, a currency strategist at UBS.As significant and potentially awful as the immediate situation is, what I find to be the most interesting element of this story is how the development and eventual resolution of this crisis reveal and potentially address the structural and logical failings of the E.M.U. system.
"Spain, Italy, Austria and Belgium -- together accounting for more than 35 percent of the euro zone economy versus just over 6 percent for Greece, Portugal and Ireland combined -- may then be next in the firing line," he added. (AP)
Does it really make sense, for example, for an economic powerhouse like Germany to share a monetary policy and currency with a much more fragile economy like Greece's? As Yves Smith points out, Germany might see the logic in to the relationship during the boom where it can trade its way into a massive surplus upon a currency cheapened by its union members. Likewise, I suspect countries such as Greece spent the better half of the last decade enjoying their ability to borrow on better terms than would otherwise be available to them (all the better to fuel a financial or a real estate bubble). But in a downturn, say, like the one we're in, such an arrangement might suddenly seem a lot less attractive for both partners.
Paul Krugman wrote the following for a lecture he is about to give to the Allied Social Science Association. It's on the slightly different issue of currency crises, but I think this excerpt is still applicable:
Suppose that the underlying problem is a level of prices and wages that makes your production uncompetitive – typically the consequence of an earlier period of excessive capital inflows. Then what must happen, sooner or later, is a decline in prices and wages relative to those in your trading partners – a real depreciation. This can happen through nominal currency depreciation – but this has the unpleasant consequence that the real value of foreign currency debt will rise, creating a deleveraging crisis.That is, in the case of a pegged and overvalued currency, the inevitable readjustment during a debt (or broader economic) crisis can come in two flavors: a downward adjustment of the currency, the "external price" of all goods and services (which will be terrible for domestic borrowers using foreign cash and consumers of foreign goods) or a downward adjustment of all "internal" prices and wages, (which will be terrible for everyone). Of course, Greece does not have a peg (though the Baltic states do), but in using the euro, it is effectively using an overvalued currency. With the euro then, Greece's hands are tied: it has no ability to conduct monetary policy and currency values are determined by the larger economic aggregate of the Eurozone.
Unfortunately, the alternative is worse. Real depreciation without nominal depreciation must take place through deflation. And this means that the real value of all debt, not just foreign- currency debt, rises. So the deleveraging crisis will be even worse if you don’t depreciate. (Krugman)
At the heart of the issue is the concept of the "optimal currency area." From its inception, because of the differentials in productivity, in language, in fiscal policies, in fiscal goals, and because of remaining constraints on factor mobility, many criticized the Eurozone for being definitively non-optimal. That is, that the European Union made more political and ideological sense--that the economic logic was missing. As Paul Krugman wrote on his blog last month:
Suppose that some members of the euro zone are hit much harder by a downturn than others, so that they have much higher-than-average unemployment; how will they adjust?However, in my mind, this is not necessarily an argument for the dissolution (or the inevitability of the dissolution of the EMU), but potentially just the opposite. If Athens and Berlin are considered illogical candidates for a mutual currency while rural Alabama and downtown Chicago are, this may very well be due to linguistic and cultural divisions, and it's certainly possible the productivity differential between those two countries is more extreme than that between those of the American example (I really have no idea). But if, as Krugman writes, more than anything else rural Alabama and downtown Chicago are able to share the almighty dollar because a broader political and economic framework exists to support that otherwise unequal pairing, that sounds like a case not for fragmentation, but further economic unification.In the United States, such shocks are cushioned by the existence of a federal government: the Social Security and Medicare checks keep being sent to Florida, even after the bubble bursts. And we adjust to a large degree with labor mobility: workers move in large numbers from depressed states to those that are doing better.
Europe lacks both the centralized fiscal system and the high labor mobility. (Yes, some workers move, but not nearly on the US scale). (TCOAL)
In this respect, the Eurozone stands in an illogical half-way house between a multi-currency system and an United States of Europe. Quoting Nouriel Roubini:
That is certainly a possibility. But it's also possible, though probably less so, that a crisis in Greece (or Spain, or Portugal, or Ireland, or...) will push the richer Eurozone members into taking the first crucial steps towards a comprehensive continental fiscal system. Either way, whether a bailout of Greece establishes an accidental precedent for future transfer payments or drachmas and pesos make a surprise reappearance in Europe, it seems like something will have to give. The maintenance of the status quo--either through a series of one-off bailouts on one hand, or total inactivity on the other, allowing the peripheral economies to wither, hoping the Eurozone will persist in its current state through pure inertia--will only postpone the resolution of Europe's structural inconsistencies until the next crisis."The eurozone could drift, essentially with a bifurcation, with a strong centre and a weaker periphery, and eventually some countries might exit the monetary union," he warned.
For all the focus on Greece, however, he also said that Spain may eventually pose an even bigger threat to the eurozone because it is the region's fourth-largest economy and has higher unemployment and weaker banks. (Independent)
Excellent post, although you lost me on some of the headier stuff. I read a really interesting article on the history of the EU that argued basically that the system as it exists today is the product of essentially what you're describing: periods of economic stress and uncertainty that provided strong incentives to increase, rather than decrease, economic and political integration. The author describes four different events, only one of which I can now remember (the end of Bretton Woods), to show that basically at each step the European nations reached the same conclusion you did and got more involved with each other.
ReplyDeleteThat's encouraging. Or at least, I think that's encouraging. For some reason, I assume a more integrated Europe is a good thing, but I'm not entirely sure why I believe that.
ReplyDelete